The selling of media rights is currently a hot
topic in European football. Last week, the English Premier League cashed in
around 7 billion Euros for the sale of its live domestic media rights (2016 to
2019) – once again a 70 percent increase in comparison to the previous tender. This
means that even the bottom club in the Premier League will receive
approximately €130 million while the champions can expect well over €200
million per season.
The Premier League’s new deal has already led
the President of the Spanish National Professional Football League (LNFP),
Javier Tebas, to express his concerns that this could see La Liga lose its position as one of Europe’s leading leagues. He reiterated
that establishing a centralised sales model in Spain is of utmost importance,
if not long overdue.
Concrete plans to reintroduce a system of joint
selling for the media rights of the Primera
División, Segunda División A, and la
Copa del Rey by means of a Royal Decree were already announced two years
ago. The road has surely been long and bumpy. The draft Decree is finally on
the table, but now it misses political approval. All the parties involved are
blaming each other for the current failure: the LNFP blames the Sport
Governmental Council for Sport (CSD) for not taking the lead; the Spanish Football
Federation (RFEF) is arguing that the Federation and non-professional
football entities should receive more money and that it should have a stronger
say in the matter in accordance with the FIFA Statutes; and there are widespread rumours that the two big earners, Real Madrid and FC Barcelona, are actively
lobbying to prevent the Royal Decree of actually being adopted.
To keep the soap opera drama flowing, on 30 December 2014, FASFE (an
organisation consisting of groups of fans, club members, and minority
shareholders of several Spanish professional football clubs) and the
International Soccer Centre (a movement that aims to obtain more balanced and
transparent football and basketball competitions in Spain) filed an antitrust complaint with the European Commission against the LNFP. They
argue that the current system of individual selling of LNFP media rights, with
unequal shares of revenue widening the gap between clubs, violates EU
competition law.
Source:http://www.gopixpic.com/600/buscar%C3%A1n-el-amor-verdadero-nueva-novela-de-televisa/http:%7C%7Cassets*zocalo*com*mx%7Cuploads%7Carticles%7C5%7C134666912427*jpg/
The complaint will surely be frowned upon in
Brussels. First, Spain is on the verge of introducing a joint selling
arrangement. So what is the point of using competition law as an instrument to
obtain … a joint selling arrangement? Second, the argument that a horizontal
agreement, preventing LNFP clubs from individually competing in the sale of
their media rights, is needed to ensure fair and effective competition seems,
to put it mildly, counterintuitive. Third, who files an antitrust complaint on
30 December?
The complainants essentially target the polarization
of revenues between the two top clubs (Real Madrid and FC Barcelona) and the
other clubs. This is a well-known and long-standing feature of the LNFP, which
is only in part attributable to disparities in the clubs’ media rights income.
The complainants point out, however, that media coverage is also an important
driver of other main revenue streams (e.g. value of sponsorship deals, ticket
sales, and merchandising).
Since the end of the 1990s, clubs have been
selling the LNFP media rights individually. In a system of individual selling,
a club’s bargaining power is evidently determined by the market potential of
the matches of a specific club and not by the collective attractiveness of the
competition as a whole. This has resulted in a pronounced imbalance between the
two top clubs Real Madrid and FC Barcelona, who are able to extract supra-normal
profits, and the other clubs.
For the 2010-2011 season, for example, the two
Spanish giants both received around €125 million for their live media rights,
leaving their domestic peers fighting over the scraps (i.e. the next biggest
clubs earned around €40 million and the majority of the clubs sold their rights
for about €15 million). In other words, Real Madrid and FC Barcelona generate
ten times more revenue from their media rights as compared to the smaller
clubs.
While it is easy to see why this situation may
be considered unfair from the perspective of the majority of the clubs, it is less
evident to find a competition law problem.
A competition law perspective
As stated above, the complaint is launched
against the LNFP who, according to FASFE, by means of authorising the individual
selling of TV rights system, is violating EU competition law.
First, the complainants argue that the system of
individual selling strengthens the dominant positions of Real Madrid and FC
Barcelona and, subsequently, undermines the competitive position of the other
clubs. So far so good. But then they jump to the conclusion that Article 102
TFEU is being violated, not by the LNFP, but by Real Madrid and FC Barcelona.
There they lost us – and presumably anyone
remotely familiar with EU competition law. But let’s be a good sport and
contemplate this line of reasoning a bit further.
It might be argued that Real Madrid and FC
Barcelona hold a (collective) dominant position on certain product markets in
Spain and, by extension, in a substantial part of the internal market – even
though the complaint fails to properly define those relevant markets. On the
upstream market for the acquisition of media rights of La Liga, both clubs
behave to a certain extent independently of their competitors. Spanish
broadcasters first seek to acquire the media rights to their matches, which
undercuts the bargaining position of the other clubs in the subsequent
negotiations for the purchase of their rights. A more fundamental flaw is that
the complainants contend that the possession or even strengthening of a
dominant position by way of competition falls within the prohibition of Article
102 TFEU. The complaint does not put forward a single argument substantiating
how both clubs engage in abusive conduct.
Second, the complainants argue that the LNFP,
according to Article 49 of its statutes, must look after the common interests
of the competitions that it organises and of its members. In their view, the
1996 decision of the LFNP General Assembly to re-introduce a system of joint
selling, which has negatively affected the majority of clubs and a large
majority of fans, does not comply with this objective.
While it can be argued that the LNFP’s decision
constitutes a decision of an association of undertakings within the meaning of
Article 101(1) TFEU, it is difficult to see how it has an anti-competitive
object or effect. Quite on the contrary, the decision lifted the competitive
constraints on the clubs’ independent decision-making that were in place up
until the season 1997-1998.
It should be noted that a system of joint
selling of media rights does not necessarily bring about an equitable
distribution of the revenues among the clubs. Albeit connected, the
distribution mechanism is a separate measure, which is typically for the most
part performance-based. Moreover, financial solidarity can also be implemented
through other mechanisms, such as a taxation system or the redistribution of
voluntary contributions. That said, it must be acknowledged that a system of
joint selling does facilitate the sharing of revenues among clubs. The ability
of sports organisers to impose alternative financial solidarity mechanisms might
be constrained by the pressure of the larger clubs (which evidently wish to see
a larger share of the revenues flow back to them because they are primarily
responsible for generating these revenues). The clubs’ media rights income
ratio in the other top European football leagues, where media rights are sold
collectively, illustrates this point. In the season 2011-2012 the earnings
ratio of the top to the bottom club was as follows: Premier League (1,55 to 1);
Serie A (4,35 to 1); Bundesliga (2,3 to 1); and Ligue 1 (3,2 to 1).[1]
Considering that joint selling only creates incentives for horizontal solidarity,
the financial solidarity justification in itself could not outweigh the
anti-competitive effects of a joint selling arrangement. The restrictions of
competition are considerable. First, joint selling agreements prevent clubs
from individually competing in the sale of their media rights. Access to the
market can therefore be foreclosed to competing buyers. Second, joint selling
leads to uniform prices and other trading conditions. Price-fixing is a
hard-core restriction that is normally prohibited. Third, joint selling could
lead to output restrictions when certain rights are withheld from the market.
As the discussion of the competition law
decisional practice below will demonstrate, it is even unclear whether the
financial solidarity argument can be invoked as a partial legal defence against
the prohibition of restrictive agreements.
The financial solidarity conundrum
One of the key assumptions underlying the
complaint is that the EU institutions advocate the joint selling of media
rights. This is presumably one of the main reasons why they are turning to
Brussels for help. While it is true that the European Council (e.g. in the 2001
Nice Declaration) and the European Parliament have always been supportive of
the link between joint selling and the principle of financial solidarity, the
same cannot be said about the European Commission. In policy documents, the
Commission has refrained from making (strong) pronouncements on the solidarity
benefits of joint selling vis-à-vis
individual selling. In the Helsinki Report on Sport (1999) the Commission underscored the need to
examine the precise link between the joint selling of media rights and
financial solidarity between professional and amateur sport. In its White Paper on Sport (2007) the Commission acknowledged that joint
selling “can be a tool for achieving
greater solidarity within sports”, but immediately added that also a system
of individual selling by clubs can be linked to a robust solidarity mechanism.
Only in the Communication on Developing the European
Dimension of Sport (2011) the
Commission expressed some general support for a system of joint selling. Surely
some of the Commission’s press releases coinciding its decisions in this area
mention benefits for financial solidarity (see e.g. here). If the complainants had looked at the actual decisions, however, they
would have realised that that rhetoric is inconsistent with the legal
argumentation.
After the need to address competition issues in
relation to joint selling arrangements for football media rights emerged in the
1990s, several National Competition Authorities (NCAs) found that the system
was incompatible with the national competition rules. The NCAs were sceptical
about the necessary link between joint selling and revenue distribution and,
subsequently, did not consider it to be a pro-competitive benefit capable of
offsetting the identified restrictive effects. Even though the NCAs spoke out uniformly
against the joint selling of football media rights, in three Member States
their decisions were either overruled by a national court (United Kingdom) or
circumvented through legislative action (Germany) or executive orders (the
Netherlands).[2]
This created uncertainties regarding the circumstances under which joint
selling could be considered compatible with EU and national competition law.
In the UEFA Champions League decision (2003) the European Commission for the first time assessed the
compatibility of the joint selling of football media rights with Article 101
TFEU. In two subsequent decisions, German Bundesliga (2005) and FA Premier League (2006), the Commission raised similar competition concerns and imposed
similar remedies to address these concerns.
In all three decisions, the Commission found
that joint selling arrangements are caught by the prohibition of Article 101(1)
TFEU, but may create substantial efficiency gains so that Article 101(3) TFEU
could be invoked as a legal defence. It identified three main benefits: (1) the
creation of a single point of sale (which creates efficiencies by reducing the
transaction costs for sports organisers and media content operators); (2)
branding of the output by one entity (which creates efficiencies as it helps the
media products receive wider recognition and distribution); and (3) the
creation of a league product focused on the competition as a whole rather than
individual clubs.
To ensure that the efficiency benefits outweigh
the toxic cocktail of anti-competitive effects (i.e. price-fixing and
considerable risks of market foreclosure and output restrictions), the
Commission carefully prescribed the way in which the rights must be marketed by
imposing a list of behavioural remedies.
Competition concern
|
Remedy
|
UEFA
|
DFB
|
FAPL
|
Risk
of foreclosure effects in downstream markets
|
Non-discriminatory
and transparent tendering procedure
|
X
|
X
|
X
|
Independent
monitoring trustee overseeing tender process
|
|
|
X
|
No
conditional bidding
|
|
|
X
|
Risk
of market foreclosure effects in downstream markets as a result of
exclusivity and bundling of media rights.
|
Limitation
of scope of exclusive contracts:
- a reasonable amount of different rights packages
- no combination of large and small packages
- earmarked packages for special markets/platforms
(new media rights)
|
X
X
|
X
X
|
X
X
X
|
Limitation
of duration of exclusive contracts: max. three football seasons
|
X
|
X
|
X
|
Risk
of output restrictions
|
Fall-back
option to clubs for unsold or unused rights
|
X
|
X
|
X
|
Parallel
exploitation of less valuable rights by clubs
|
X
|
|
|
Risk
of monopolisation
|
“No
single buyer” obligation
|
|
|
X
|
In all three of the Commission’s investigations,
the parties put forward the financial solidarity argument as the main
justification for an exemption of their joint selling arrangements under
Article 101(3) TFEU.[3]
Yet the Commission never substantially addressed that argument. Only in the UEFA Champions League decision, the
point was briefly considered. The Commission simply noted that UEFA had failed
to substantiate the indispensability of a joint selling agreement for the
redistribution of revenue and, subsequently, for the organisation of the
Champions League.[4] Since
it could exempt the joint selling agreement on economic efficiency grounds, however,
the Commission concluded that “it is not
necessary for the purpose of this procedure to consider the solidarity argument
any further”.[5] As
such, the Commission conveniently got round the issue.
The national decisional practice subsequent to
the Commission’s precedents equally refrained from addressing the issue. The
NCAs started focusing their assessments exclusively on efficiency benefits, as
instructed by the Commission.
In short, in competition law proceedings related
to joint selling arrangements, the financial solidarity defence has never been
very compelling – it was either considered unsound (early national enforcement
practice) or remained unaddressed. Of course, one may still argue that the
elephant in the room was surreptitiously taken into account (bearing in mind
that the acceptance of a similar price-fixing cartel in other sectors would be
difficult to imagine).[6]
Redistribution formulas for media rights income
After the European Commission de facto legitimized the joint selling
of football media rights, the system became the common practice for marketing
such rights in Europe. Since Italy reintroduced the system of joint selling in
2010, Cyprus, Portugal, and Spain are now the last EU markets in which first
division football clubs sell their rights individually.
To put the distribution key foreseen in the
pending Spanish Royal Decree into perspective, we will first summarize how the
other four big European leagues redistribute the media rights income.
England: Since 1992, the year in which the Premier
League was formed, it was decided that 50% of the revenue is split equally between
the 20 clubs, 25% is paid in Merit Payments (depending on where a club finishes
in the final League table), and the final 25% is paid in Facility Fees (based
on each time a club’s matches are broadcast in the UK). All international
broadcast revenue, and central commercial revenue, is split equally amongst the
20 clubs. For the season 2013/2014, the ratio between the top (Liverpool at €132
million Euros) and the bottom earning club (Cardiff City at €84 million) was
1.57:1.
Germany: Within the German Bundesliga
clubs, the criteria for the distribution of
revenues
will be determined by a 2:1 ratio between the top-ranked and the bottom-ranked
teams in an ad hoc distribution ranking for the years 2013 – 2017. This means
that the revenue sharing distribution will range from a maximum of 5.8% of the
total amount for the first place team to at least 2.9% for the 18th place team.
The Bundesliga’s international media rights income distribution, however,
remains based on both international and domestic sport performance.
Italy: Italy’s Serie A joint selling system had an
earnings ratio of the top to bottom club of 5.25:1 for the season 2013/2014. Juventus,
the top earning club, had an income from TV rights of €94 million, whereas the
bottom earning club, Sassuolo, of €17.9 million.[7] Out
of the total amount distributed, 40% is distributed to all the clubs as a fixed
amount. Furthermore, 30% is distributed on the basis of past results (15% on
results during last five seasons, 10% on historical results[8],
and 5% on last season’s final league position); and 25% according to club
supporters base.
The planned Royal Decree in Spain will have a distribution system that
guarantees Real Madrid and FC Barcelona an amount that is very close to what
they earn now. The income ratio of the clubs will start at 4:1 and diminishes
as the total amount of income increases. From the total income, about 3% will
be deducted for the Spanish FA and for non-professional sports. Additionally,
10% will be assigned to the Second Division. The remaining amount will be
distributed as follows: 50% as fixed amount for all the clubs, 25% depending on
sports results while taking into account historical results. The other 25% will
be distributed in relation to public awareness similar the Italian system
(calculated on the basis of TV audiences, city population, and number of fans
of the club).
Conclusion
It is safe to say that the competition complaint
launched by FASFE will not lead to the European Commission opening a formal
investigation. The complainants fail to demonstrate how the current Spanish
individual selling system breaches, or even potentially breaches, Article 101
and/or 102 TFEU. In that regard, it should be noted that they already tried
their luck with the national competition authority (CNC), alleging
infringements of national competition law. On 8 January 2013, the CNC decided
to reject the complaint because it only prescribed the results of the current
media rights sales process without demonstrating violations of the national
competition rules.
Whether FASFE is aware of the same judicial
inaccuracies in its Commission complaint is unknown. On the other hand, it is
quite evident that invoking competition law to argue for the introduction of a
cartel with significant anti-competitive effects is paradoxical. The ex
post fairness (i.e. the outcome of market competition) that FASFE is
looking for is quite different from the ex
ante fairness in the market place that competition policy is concerned
with. One can therefore interpret
the complaint as an attempt to add pressure on the involved Spanish parties (the
CSD, the LNFP, and the RFEF) to introduce the new Royal Decree once and for
all. Although the Spanish public is provided daily episodes full of jabbering,
backstabbing and other drama, as with all Telenovelas,
the soap is dragging on and on and should have ended ages ago.
Whether the switch to
a joint selling arrangement will significantly improve the competitive balance
in La Liga remains to be seen. Since
FC Barcelona and Real Madrid are guaranteed an amount similar to what they
receive now, this will ultimately depend on how much the total income from the
sale of the media rights will increase. The inexorable
rise in the value of the broadcasting deals in the UK, which is the unique
result of a duopoly of two powerful deep-pocket players (i.e. the incumbent
dominant pay-TV operator Sky and new market entrant BT) that emerged after the
introduction of the “no single buyer” obligation, cannot be realistically
expected – at least not in the short term. Yet it is relatively certain that
the overall income from media rights will go up – ultimately to the benefit of
all the clubs. A (minimum) earnings ratio of the top to bottom club of 4:1 is
not overly ambitious, but surely is a welcome step towards remedying the
current imbalance between the two top clubs and their less fortunate
competitors.
[1] See T.M.C. Asser Institute and
Institute for Information Law, “Study on Sports Organisers' Rights in the EU”,
Commissioned by the European Commission, DG Education and Culture, February
2014.
[2] Idem.
[3] See e.g.
Commission, “Case No IV/37.214 - DFB - Central marketing of TV and radio
broadcasting rights for certain football competitions in Germany” (Notice)
(1999) OJ C/610, para. 7; Commission, “Notice published pursuant to Article
19(3) of Council Regulation No 17 concerning case COMP/C.2/38.173 and 38.453 -
joint selling of the media rights of the FA Premier League on an exclusive
basis” (2004) OJ C 115/3, para. 10.
[4] UEFA Champions League (Case COMP/37.398) Commission
decision 2003/778/EC (2003) OJ L291/25, para. 131.
[5] Idem, para. 167.
[6] See e.g.
Giorgio Monti, “Article 81 EC and Public Policy” (2002) 39 CMLR 1057 (calling
it a “sector-specific exemption”).
[7] FASFE Antitrust
Complaint of 30 December 2014, page 11
[8] In other words, this
revenue is determined by overall league placings since 1946. In this category,
Juventus, AC Milan and Inter Milan are the top earning clubs. For more info
see: http://www.financialfairplay.co.uk/latest-news/tv-revenue-distribution-%E2%80%93-comparing-italian-and-english-models.